DOI: 10.7256/2454-065X.2023.1.39483
EDN: LJOGII
Received:
23-12-2022
Published:
08-01-2023
Abstract:
Economic growth is the most important condition for dynamic socio-economic development of any country. The problems of tax stimulation of economic growth in Russia are of particular relevance due to the fact that its indicators are very unstable, for many years the target values have never been achieved, and the efficiency of the tax instruments involved has been much lower than expected. The purpose of this paper is to study the main problems of tax stimulation of economic growth in Russia in connection with the new industrial revolution and to determine its prospective directions. The research methodology is based on the integrated application of the tools of analysis and synthesis; quantitative economic analysis and analysis of tax buoyancy are used to substantiate the main conclusions. Scientific novelty of the research is associated with the substantiation of conceptual provisions of tax stimulation of economic growth in the Russian Federation, the distinctive feature of which is the focus on the formation of a tax regime favorable to it, with a focus on the possibilities of digitalization. The necessity of transition from stimulation of economic growth through the mechanism of corporate income taxation to tax stimulation encouraging investments and innovations through other, more reliable mechanisms in the conditions of digitalization was substantiated. Application of the results: the Ministry of Finance and the Federal Tax Service can use the results of the study in determining the proactive tax policy in the Russian Federation in terms of tax incentives for economic growth.
Keywords:
taxes, tax policy, corporate income tax, tax incentives, tax benefits, economic growth, economic mainstream, digitalization, Fourth Industrial Revolution, tax administration
This article is automatically translated.
The problem of stimulating economic growth in the Russian Federation, as a necessary condition for socio-economic development, has been of priority importance for several decades. It is often emphasized in the annual messages of the President of the Russian Federation V. V. Putin to the Federal Assembly, including since the first 2000. At the same time, the need for sustainable growth, its causes and vulnerability to external factors is emphasized. In 2003, the head of state set the task of doubling the GDP. Today, ensuring economic growth in Russia above the global average by 2030 while maintaining macroeconomic stability is defined as one of the indicators of achieving the national goal of "Decent, effective work and successful entrepreneurship" [1]. At the same time, as shown in Fig. 1, the indicators of economic growth in modern Russia are very unstable, for many years it has not been possible to achieve the target values. At the same time, there is a noticeable significant lag from the similar indicator of the economies of India and China, which are already in the desired range for the Russian economy and indicate the reality of achieving the stated strategic targets.
Fig. 1. Comparative dynamics of economic growth indicators in 2010-2021.Source: built by the authors according to the World Bank [2] The last decade has turned out to be very difficult for Russia due to the fact that the country has faced the most serious challenges, including the need to update production processes based on the technologies of the Fourth Industrial Revolution, the pandemic of a new coronavirus infection, the most complex geopolitical crisis and unprecedented economic sanctions. Of course, all this could not but affect economic growth. However, today it is already obvious that the series of exogenous shocks that have occurred has determined new conditions for the development of Russia, which require and make possible the adoption of cardinal decisions in a variety of areas, including in the practice of tax incentives for economic growth. The scientific justification of tax incentives for economic growth comes from the operational provisions of economic theory in the relevant subject area, verified (at least partially) through empirical research [3-5]. The approach to the study of the impact of taxes on economic growth associated with its exogenous and endogenous theories has become widespread in the financial mainstream [3, 6]. The theory of exogenous economic growth, developed back in the 1950s and 1960s [7], considers it as a result of capital accumulation, and an increase in labor productivity – technological progress. Usually the emphasis is on capital accumulation, and as for technological progress, it is assumed that it is due to some external – exogenous – variables. Exogenous growth models are based on the production function, where capital and labor are factors, which can be objects of taxation. One of the important conclusions for the policy of tax stimulation of economic growth, justified on the basis of the theory of exogenous economic growth, was the conclusion of K. Chamley that in the long term the optimal tax on capital income should be zero [8, p. 619]. Unlike growth that depends on external factors, the theory of endogenous growth proceeds from the fact that it is generated within the economic system itself as a direct result of its internal processes. At the same time, a number of explanations for economic growth are proposed, such as increasing human capital, better provision of public goods (through investments in education, healthcare, infrastructure, research and development), search by economic entities for profitable investments, etc. It is obvious that tax policy can influence all these processes and, consequently, economic growth. One of the latest studies on tax policy in the context of endogenous growth driven by innovation was carried out by T. Gross and P. Klein (2022), who proved that in the short term capital can be taxed, but in the long term it should be subsidized, and the question of whether taxes on innovation should be positive or negative, depending on the amount of government spending, the strength of the external effects of innovation and the market power of patent holders [9]. The contribution of Russian scientists to the analysis of the problems of tax incentives for economic growth is also significant. In particular, E. Balatsky in a number of scientific papers developed A. Laffer's concept of the impact of the general level of taxation on production and budget revenues [10, p. 34]; a researcher together with N. Ekimova constructed dependences of the growth rates of the production of branches of the Russian economy on the level of the industry tax burden and made an important conclusion that the sensitivity to the tax burden depends on the level of technology of the industry [11]. In the works of V. G. Panskov, the tax policy implemented in the Russian Federation is analyzed, a conclusion is made about sufficient consistency and a certain unsystematic nature, which led to the formation of an inflated level of tax burden that hinders the growth of investments [12]. V. G. Panskov also shows that the current instruments of tax regulation are not able to facilitate the attraction of funds by business entities for their M. D. Abramov and V. A. Kashin systematically investigated the impact of taxation on the processes of socio-economic development in Russia, and came to the disappointing conclusion that "taxes are against development" [14]. At the same time, it should be noted that a number of tax barriers to economic development, including the inefficiency of VAT tax administration, high labor costs for preparing tax reports, are successfully removed during the digitalization of relevant processes by tax authorities, while the proposals of specialists regarding progressive taxation of personal income as the most important condition for socio-economic development are not new and are very debatable nature. The comprehensive approach and completeness of the study distinguishes the work [15], in which the whole set of tax instruments available at the regional level to stimulate the investment activity of economic entities is analyzed, their comparison with progressive foreign experience is carried out. The purpose of this work is to study the aspects of tax incentives for economic growth in Russia in connection with the new industrial revolution and the digitalization of the economy and to identify its promising areas. The formation and development of the modern Russian tax system took place in the conditions of orientation to the Western European model of economic construction, which, in the conditions of the then boundless optimism about pro-Western globalization, was considered as the only true, in fact, universal. At the same time, the tax mainstream, striving for the widest coverage of the most diverse processes and phenomena, was usually based on explicit or implicit assumptions about the uniformity of people's behavior (their universal rationality or limited rationality, regardless of direct dependence on technological, cultural, institutional factors) and the societies they created, and therefore usually did not take into account the specific circumstances of the place and time. The consequence of this is that Russian legislation today reflects in one way or another all the main tax instruments for stimulating economic growth that are used in practice in most countries of the world. Most of these instruments are associated with benefits and preferences for corporate income tax, and the tax instruments themselves are designed to stimulate the activation of investment and innovation activities of organizations, including: - nonlinear (accelerated) depreciation; - increasing coefficients to depreciation rates; - "depreciation premium", which allows you to allocate from 10 to 30% of the cost of purchased fixed assets and/or their completion, reconstruction, modernization to expenses; - increasing ratio to R&D expenses; - investment tax deduction for corporate income tax; - investment tax credit and others.
Reduced or zero corporate income tax rates are applied by residents of special economic zones (SEZ), territories of advanced socio-economic development (TOCER), participants of free economic zones (SEZ), the Skolkovo Innovation Center, regional investment contracts (RIP), special investment contracts (SPIC) and other separate categories of organizations. Of course, tax benefits aimed at stimulating economic growth are also applied to other taxes (for example, an investment tax deduction for personal income tax, a set of preferential conditions for property taxes for SEZ residents, VAT exemption for R&D performed at the expense of the budget, and performed by scientific and educational organizations, etc.), However, the greatest result is stillthe same was expected from the benefits of corporate income tax. At the same time, as the analysis shows, neither business nor the state are quite satisfied with the available tools. For business, the application of tax benefits is often considered as quite costly (for example, in connection with the registration of various documents required to qualify for benefits) and risky actions. Thus, experts note that "regarding the legality of the application of tax benefits, there are a huge number of disputes, which are most often associated with a different understanding of the purposes of their establishment, the rules for their use, as well as the authority to put benefits into effect" [15, p. 182]. Profit tax benefits are meaningless when, for example, at the initial stage an organization does not yet have a profit, but there is a need to make capital investments and an obligation to pay other taxes. communication of authors with business representatives. In addition, in the communication of the authors with business representatives, the message from the latter quite often sounds that the corporate income tax can be effectively planned and quite legally optimized, and therefore it does not form the main tax burden. On the part of the state, the key issue related to the provision of tax benefits related to stimulating economic growth is expected to be the issue of their effectiveness. The Accounts Chamber of the Russian Federation has repeatedly drawn attention to the ineffectiveness of certain benefits, and its report published in early 2020 indicates that the zones created in the country with preferential tax regimes have still not had a "breakthrough impact" [16]. It should be noted that the executive power was also very concerned about the assessment of the effectiveness of tax, including investment benefits, and carried out systematic work in this regard, including those related to methodological recommendations for assessing the effectiveness of tax expenditures, which should be carried out by curators of tax expenditures [17, 18]. At the same time, the effectiveness of such activities still remained low. Significant, and in our opinion reasonable, hopes in solving this problem are pinned on the joint development of the Ministry of Finance and the Federal Tax Service of Russia presented in the fall of 2022 - the analytical system "Efficiency of benefits" [19]. Since the new system is built on the basis of AIS "Tax-3", this means that it will use the most up-to-date and accurate information about each taxpayer applying a particular tax benefit. In fact, this tool will be able, as in the case of VAT administration reform, to maximize the benefits of the possibilities of using modern information technologies, processing and analysis of big data. An investment tax benefit is recognized as effective if the taxpayer who applies it achieves an increase in operational profitability and return on assets, and at the same time, the most important point is that this taxpayer increases investments, R&D volumes, and the wage fund. Otherwise, the benefit is considered ineffective. If the inefficient use of benefits is recorded by more than 70% of all taxpayers, then the benefit needs to be adjusted. As noted by Deputy Finance Minister A.Sazanov, the results of the work of the new analytical system "Efficiency of benefits" showed that additional adjustment is necessary for 12 preferential regimes, verified by the Ministry of Finance, operating in the Russian Federation, related to the application of investment tax benefits (including SEZ, SPIC, investment tax deduction for corporate income tax, etc.). Official He designated 2024 as the period when additional adjustment measures should be implemented in the tax legislation. The government is also not entirely satisfied with the sectoral distribution of benefits from investment tax benefits. Thus, with a general assessment of the corresponding tax expenditures at the level of 2.4 trillion rubles, the lion's share - 83.3% (about 2 trillion rubles) falls on the oil and gas sector, and the remaining 16.7% (400 billion rubles) is mainly used by the largest companies in traditional sectors of the Russian economy [20]. Thus, the problem of inefficiency of investment tax benefits currently in force in Russia is, in fact, explicitly recognized by the state authorities, which means that well-thought-out, systematic recommendations are needed to solve it. In this context, first of all, it is important to emphasize that, firstly, tax incentives for economic growth should be carried out in accordance with the requirements of the Strategy of Scientific and Technological Development of the Russian Federation [21], which is aimed at obtaining high scientific and scientific and technical results and creating technologies that are the basis for the innovative development of the domestic market of products and services, as well as Russia's stable position in the foreign market, including advanced digital and intelligent technologies, robotic systems, new materials, clean energy technologies, highly productive and environmentally friendly agro- and aquatic farming, etc. – that is, everything that reflects the essence of the Fourth Industrial Revolution, which Russia should enter as one of the world leaders in selected areas of scientific and technological development within both traditional and new markets of technologies, products and services. And, secondly, tax incentives for economic growth should not contradict the strategic orientation to maintain macroeconomic stability in the Russian Federation, which is of priority importance from the standpoint of national security. In this regard, the fiscal system has a certain potential and room for maneuver, since in recent years it has generally been distinguished by a high level of balance and a low level of debt denominated mainly in national currency [22, p. 21], and, in addition, further improvement of tax collection by digital tax administration methods, etc.
Today it is important to properly use this potential, based on the understanding that the previous model of economic development of the Russian Federation, based on the export of hydrocarbons, the exploitation of cheap resources, including labor, and the import of finished products, has clearly exhausted itself [23]. Therefore, it is necessary, using the new "windows of opportunity" that the Fourth Industrial Revolution opens, to form a long-term, stable, transparent for business and society proactive tax policy aimed at solving a set of interrelated tasks: with a general course to create a generally favorable tax regime for business, primarily the sector of small and medium-sized enterprises, necessary for the normal functioning of a complete ecosystem of economic entities, the growth of employment and the welfare of citizens, to provide systematic support for production technologies that are key to national security and economic growth, while shifting reformist accents to aspects of digitalization. The profit of organizations in modern conditions is losing its importance both as a regulator of economic processes and as an object of taxation. Firstly, because purely market regulators – and profit is the central link of market regulation – are losing their importance due to the beginning of a new industrial revolution. At this initial stage, as is well known, it is necessary to focus more on indicators of technological efficiency, rather than market (economic) efficiency [24]. The importance of technological efficiency and technological sovereignty is increasing even more due to the problem of exogenous shocks, which include Western economic sanctions against the Russian Federation. Under these conditions, the market mechanism of industrial policy, which the government has traditionally focused on, does not work reliably enough. As a result, at a critical moment, the country did not have its own equipment and technologies in a number of areas. For example, in the production of building materials, dependence on imported supplies is up to 40%, and in the food and textile industry – up to 60-80%. [25, p. 6]. Therefore, now at the level of the central government, the transition from a market industrial policy to a policy of ensuring technological sovereignty, where, obviously, the current profit, on the basis of which the tax is calculated, it will not be the main guideline. Secondly, because the income tax, in principle, does not work well in the conditions of the dominant trend towards digitalization in the world. At the global level, there are already serious claims to it, since TNCs in the conditions of digitalization get away from this tax relatively easily, which leads to an unfair distribution of wealth and deepening inequality in the world. This became the basis for a decision at the international level to introduce a global minimum tax rate and redistribute part of tax rights between countries depending on the place of origin of income, which is obviously a palliative solution. Similar problems arise in the Russian Federation, and not only in relation to TNCs, but also domestic enterprises, which, thanks to digitalization, have objectively received more opportunities to engage in tax planning (as already noted above). The problems of corporate profit taxation were clearly manifested in 2022, when unprecedented economic sanctions were imposed against the Russian Federation by the collective West. Figure 2 clearly shows a significant drop in corporate income tax receipts. Compared to the IV quarter of 2021, real corporate income tax receipts decreased in the I-III quarters of 2022 by 14.8%, 26.03% and 56.69%, respectively. At the same time, the reduction of all real tax revenues was determined at the level of 19.92, 27.71 and 45.91%. At the same time, receipts for corporate income tax in the third quarter of 2022 became less than receipts from VAT and personal income tax, and it moved to the third position for the first time in recent years. Fig. 2. Dynamics of tax revenues in the budget system of the Russian FederationSource: calculated by the authors according to tax reporting data in the form of 1-NM [26], taking into account the values of quarterly GDP deflator indices in 1-3 quarters of 2022 [27]. It should be noted that in world practice, when forming tax policy, special tools are used related to the calculation and analysis of sensitivity indicators (tax buoyancy) and elasticity (tax elasticity) of tax revenues both in general and for certain types of taxes [28]. At the same time, for certain reasons, the sensitivity indicator has been more widely used, which is calculated according to the formula:
where LF i is the sensitivity for tax revenues for the i-th type of taxes; %? Tax receipts - percentage change in tax provisions for the i-th type of taxes; %? of GDP is the percentage change in GDP. Tax sensitivity shows by how many percent tax revenues increase/decrease with an increase/decrease in GDP by one percent. It is important that the growth of tax indicators with this method of calculating the indicator is not solely related to GDP growth, but is determined by the totality of relevant factors (including, for example, changes in tax rates, tax administration efficiency, exogenous shocks, etc.). The results of the calculations are presented in the table. It can be seen that gradually tax revenues are becoming less sensitive to the reduction of GDP. In general, the same dynamics characterizes the sensitivity of tax revenues from income tax. Table 1 - Tax sensitivity for the aggregate of tax revenues and individual types of taxes I quarter 2022 | II quarter 2022 | III quarter 2022 | Tax revenues | 0,0551 | | 0,0140 | 0,0123 | Corporate income tax | 0,0410 | 0,0190 | 0,0203 | VAT0,0137 | | 0,0387 | 0,0032 | VAT on goods (works, services) sold on the territory of the Russian Federation | 0,0107 | 0,0401 | 0,0034 | VAT on goods imported into the territory of the Russian Federation | 0,0624 | 0,0105 | 0,0000 | Personal income tax 0,1041 | | 0,0180 | -0,0037 | Other taxes0,0590 | | -0,0038 | 0,0169 | Source: calculated by the authors based on tax reporting data in the form of 1-NM [26] and quarterly GDP indicators, taking into account the values of quarterly GDP deflator indices in 1-3 quarters of 2022 [27]. However, the sensitivity of corporate income tax to a decrease in GDP in the third quarter of 2022, when the tax system has already adapted to the conditions formed as a result of the start of a special military operation, is almost twice as high as the sensitivity of the entire set of tax revenues to the budget system of the Russian Federation and is an order of magnitude higher than the sensitivity of VAT and personal income tax receipts. Of course, this is a preliminary conclusion that requires additional empirical verification based on data from future periods. It seems that the tax incentives for economic growth embedded in the current mechanism of corporate income tax during the crisis and recession are losing their significance for many taxpayers, since the tax itself is not paid or is paid in relatively small amounts due to the reduction of the tax base. All of the above allows the authors to propose the following conceptual solution for the Russian tax system – the transition from incentives through the mechanism of taxation of profits of organizations (bearing in mind that the benefits of this tax do not work well as an economic incentive) to tax incentives that encourage investment and innovation through other, more reliable mechanisms in the conditions of digitalization. This implies: 1) the rejection of corporate income tax in favor of an alternative that lends itself well to digital algorithmization (does not require special accounting and always controversial comparison of numerous and diverse elements of gross costs and results for the reporting period), does not burden investments, i.e. resources introduced into the business, and taxes only resources derived from business; 2) the creation of a new, transparent and understandable for business entities digital mechanism of tax incentives for economic growth in the form of tax credits, provided they meet the qualification requirements in terms of R&D and investment. A fundamentally new and important point of the proposed tax instrument should be that the digital tax investment and innovation loan is the allocation of digital rubles to the accounts of economic entities that can use them to repay tax obligations of their choice for any of the taxes accrued to them. The Bank of Russia is actively working on the widespread use of digital rubles at the moment. Their indisputable advantage is the possibility of their "colored" application. Therefore, the provision of a digital tax credit is, on the one hand, a potential opportunity for effective control over the targeted nature of the use of digital money using blockchain technology. And, on the other hand, it is an increase in the degrees of freedom of economic entities in terms of the use of resources allocated by the state.
It should also be noted that economic entities are objectively very different and react differently to tax incentives. Therefore, an effective system of tax incentives should also be differentiated. Economic coordination in the modern world has at least two forms: market coordination, which operates mainly in the sphere of small and medium-sized businesses, and hierarchical coordination, which is common for large businesses and large corporations, primarily state-owned ones. These are different ways of economic existence and different behavioral (including tax) patterns, which were written about by J. K. Galbraith (market and planning systems) [29]. For example, the main means of communication in the mechanism of market coordination are prices, and in the hierarchical one – routines [30]. Therefore, for medium and small businesses, tax incentives are more important, which reduce market prices for consumed and invested resources for them, and for large businesses – institutional stability and the ability to control the environment, which is achieved, among other things, through lobbying and special contracts with the state (SPIC, NWPC). Conclusions. Solving the urgent problem of tax incentives for economic growth in Russia in the context of the Fourth Industrial Revolution requires the formation of a new fiscal environment corresponding to the new digital realities, which encourages savings, investment and innovation, labor and entrepreneurial activity in accordance with the priorities defined by the Strategy of Scientific and Technological Development of the Russian Federation. At the same time, the set of proposed measures should not contradict the policy of maintaining macroeconomic stability, which is of fundamental importance from the standpoint of national security. This requires the formation of a long-term, stable, transparent for business and society proactive (proactive) tax policy. It should be aimed at solving a complex of interrelated tasks: with a general course to create a generally favorable tax regime for business, primarily the SME sector, necessary for the normal functioning of a complete ecosystem of economic entities, employment growth and welfare of citizens, to provide systematic support for production technologies key to national security and economic growth with a shift in reform emphasis on aspects of digitalization. Digitalization creates not only new opportunities, in particular in the field of tax administration, which has already made it possible to fundamentally improve the mechanism of VAT collection, but also new problems that call into question the potential of the traditional corporate income tax, which has already been clearly manifested in the conditions of economic sanctions. Therefore, it is important to once again consider the issue of abandoning the current corporate income tax in favor of switching to a new form of this tax, which lends itself well to digital algorithmization, does not burden investments, i.e. resources introduced into business, but only taxes resources withdrawn from business. The tax on withdrawn capital and the tax on cash flows at the destination can be considered as candidates. It may also be important to develop special tax incentive mechanisms, which, due to their purposefulness and selectivity, can be effective in solving the problem of accelerating economic growth. This is, in particular, due to the peculiarities of the current stage of development – the emergence of new technologies of the Fourth Industrial Revolution based on the achievements of digitalization and the Internet, the successful promotion and dissemination of which in the Russian economy requires special support. In this regard, in addition to the further development of the SPIC and NWPC mechanisms, it is important to provide economic entities with new, more advanced tax incentives for the development of production based on the use of the potential of the digital ruble, the targeted use of which is guaranteed by blockchain technology. But this issue requires further in-depth research, including in connection with the expected transformations of the entire mechanism of financing the Russian economy in the new geopolitical conditions.
References
1. President of Russia (2020). Decree of the President of the Russian Federation from 21.07.2020 ¹ 474 «On the national development goals of the Russian Federation for the period up to 2030». Retrieved from http://kremlin.ru/events/president/news/63728 (access date: 10.11.2022).
2. GDP growth (annual %). World Bank national accounts data, and OECD National Accounts data files. Retrieved from https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZG (access date: November 10.11.2022).
3. Myles, G.D. (2007). Economic Growth and the Role of Taxation. Prepared for the OECD: University of Exeter and Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2007.
4. OECD (2020). Tax Policy Reforms 2020: OECD and Selected Partner Economies. OECD Publishing, Paris, 2020, 122p doi: 10.1787/7af51916-en.
5. Alinaghi, N., Reed, W.R.. (2021) Taxes and Economic Growth in OECD Countries: A Meta-analysis. Public Finance Review, Vol. 49(10), 3-40. doi: 10.1177/1091142120961775.
6. Myles, G.D. (2000). Taxation and Economic Growth. Fiscal Studies, Vol. 21, no. 1, 141-168.
7. Solow, R.M. (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 70, 65-94.
8. Chamley, C. (986). Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilibrium with Infinite Lives. Econometrica, Vol. 54, No. 3, 607-622. https://doi.org/10.2307/1911310.
9. Gross, T., Klein, P. (2022) Optimal tax policy and endogenous growth through innovation. Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 209, 104645. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2022.104645
10. Balatsky, E.V. (2020). Efficiency of fiscal policy of the state. Problems of Forecasting, ¹5, 32-45.
11. Balatsky, E.V., Ekimova, N.A. (2020) Evaluation of Russian Economic Sectors' Sensitivity to Tax Burden. Journal of Tax Reform, Vol. 6(2), 157-179. https://doi.org/10.15826/jtr.2020.6.2.080
12. Pansková V.G. (2022). Priorities of tax policy and directions of reforming of Russian tax system . ETAP: economic theory, analysis, practice, ¹ 1, 57-76. doi: 10.24412/2071-6435-2022-1-57-76.
13. Panskov, V.G. (2021). New depreciation policy as an instrument of tax regulation. Economics and Management: problems, solutions.. Vol. 4, ¹ 4 (112),. 35-41. doi: 10.36871/ek.up.p.r.2021.04.04.007
14. Abramov, M.D., Kashin, V.A. (2016) Taxes against development (While taxes win): Ìoscow.
15. Mandroshchenko, O.V. (Ed.). (2021). Tax instruments in the implementation of regional investment policy: a monograph. Moscow: Publishing and Trading Corporation "Dashkov and Co".
16. Accounts Chamber of Russia. (2018).Report on the results «Analysis of achieving the national goals "Ensuring sustainable growth of real incomes of citizens, as well as the growth of pension provision above the inflation rate" and "Halving the poverty rate in the Russian Federation", established in the Decree of the President of the Russian Federation of May 7, 2018 ¹ 204 "On national goals and strategic tasks of the Russian Federation for the period up to 2024». Retrieved from https://ach.gov.ru/upload/iblock/3c9/3c911347504f7a96ff67c94e7ed7d2a6.pdf. (access date: 10.11.2022).
17. The Government Decree of the Russian Federation from April 12, 2019 ¹ 439 "On approval of the Rules of forming the list of tax expenditures of the Russian Federation and assessment of tax expenditures of the Russian Federation".
18. Clarifications on the application of the provisions of the Rules for the formation of the list of tax expenditures of the Russian Federation and the assessment of tax expenditures of the Russian Federation. Retrieved from https://minfin.gov.ru/common/upload/library/2021/12/main/Razyasneniya_po_otsenke_NR_RF_fin.pdf (access date: 10.11.2022).
19. The Ministry of Finance and FTS of Russia presented the analytical system "Efficiency of benefits" at FF-22. Retrieved from https://www.nalog.gov.ru/rn77/news/activities_fts/12466806/ (access date: 10.11.2022).
20. The Ministry of Finance plans to fine-tune tax benefits for business in early 2023 // Vedomosti. Retrieved from https://www.vedomosti.ru/economics/articles/2022/11/21/951247-minfin-planiruet-donastroiku-nalogovih-lgot-dlya-biznesa (date of reference: 22.11.2022).
21. President of Russia (2016). Decree of the President of the Russian Federation from 01.12.2016 ¹ 642 "On the Strategy of scientific and technological development of the Russian Federation". Retrieved from http://kremlin.ru/acts/bank/41449 (access date: 10.11.2022).
22. Mau, V.A. (2022). Economic policy in pandemic conditions: the experience of 2021-2022. Voprosy ekonomiki, No. 3, 5-28. doi: 10.32609/0042-8736-2022-3-5-28.
23. Vishnevskii, V.P., Goncharenko, L.I., Nikulkina, I.V., Gurnak, A.V. (2020). Taxes and technologies: past, present and future of the tax system in Russia. Terra Economicus, No. 18(4), 6-31. doi: 10.18522/2073-6606-2020-18-4-6-31
24. Perez, K. (2011). Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital. The Dynamics of Bubbles and Periods of Golden Ages. Translated from English by F.V. Majewski. Moscow: Delo.
25. Denis Manturov in Search of Technological Sovereignty Reached the Deputy Prime Minister / / Expert, 2022, ¹ 29.
26. Reports on accrual and receipt of taxes, fees, insurance premiums and other obligatory payments. Federal Tax Service of Russia (official website). Retrieved from https://www.nalog.gov.ru/rn77/related_activities/statistics_and_analytics/forms/ (access date: 10.11.2022).
27. National accounts. Gross domestic product. GDP quarters (since 1995). Federal State Statistics Service (official website). Retrieved from https://rosstat.gov.ru/statistics/accounts (date of reference: 10.11.2022).
28. Jenkins, G.P., Chun-Yan Kuo, Shukla, G.P. (2000). Tax Analysis and Revenue Forecasting. Issues and Techniques. Harvard Institute for International Development. Harvard University, 2000. 191p. Retrieved from https://www.cri-world.com/publications/qed_dp_169.pdf (access date: 10.11.2022).
29. Galbraith, J. (1979). Economics and the Public Purpose. Translated from English: Moscow: Progress.
30. Powell, W. (1990). Neither Market nor Hierarchy: Network Forms of Organization. Research in Organizational Behaviour, Vol. 12, 295-336
First Peer Review
Peer reviewers' evaluations remain confidential and are not disclosed to the public. Only external reviews, authorized for publication by the article's author(s), are made public. Typically, these final reviews are conducted after the manuscript's revision. Adhering to our double-blind review policy, the reviewer's identity is kept confidential.
The list of publisher reviewers can be found here.
The subject of the study. The article, based on the title, should be devoted to tax incentives for economic growth in Russia. The content of the article is extremely indirectly consistent with the stated research topic. First of all, due to the author's contribution to the solution of the issues stated in the title. The research methodology is based on the presentation of well-known facts and judgments contained in the scientific works of other authors. The author of the reviewed materials has built one table, but it is not clear from the text: is this the result of the author's research or is it borrowed from any publication? If this is an author's development, then it is necessary to indicate under the table what is "developed by the author", if the table is prepared based on the results of familiarization with any/if there are any sources, then the following words should be added after the words "compiled by the author": "based on ... (specify the source)" The relevance of the study of tax incentives for economic growth in the Russian Federation is beyond doubt, because it fully meets the national interests of our state, including the national development goals of the Russian Federation for the period up to 2030. And to ensure it, it is necessary to use all the tools available in the arsenal, including tax ones, as efficiently and effectively as possible. There is no scientific novelty in the material submitted for review, as there are no author's research results. Style, structure, content. The style of presentation is scientific, if assessed by the fact of the absence of colloquial, colloquial and journalistic words and phrases. The structure of the article is built incorrectly, because in fact it contains only one block: "the study of literary sources on the chosen research topic." At the same time, and from a substantive point of view, it is revealed extremely superficially: since there is absolutely no author's assessment of the research results obtained in the publications under study. It seems incorrect to use the abbreviation "RF" in a scientific article (it is allowed to use only names permitted by the Constitution of the Russian Federation). As part of solving problems with structure and content, it is recommended: first, to supplement the blocks devoted to the analysis of numerical data on the issues under consideration, to search for problems based on it and to develop a reasonable set of recommendations for their solution. Meaningful alignment with the national development goals of the Russian Federation for the period up to 2030 is also welcome. Bibliography. The author has compiled a bibliographic list of 16 sources. It seems that the domestic scientific literature on tax incentives for economic growth in the Russian Federation has not been sufficiently studied. Moreover, the list of sources should be drawn up according to the requirements of GOST. Appeal to opponents. Given the fact that there are no scientific results obtained based on the results of the research conducted by the author, the author did not even have the prerequisites and grounds for conducting any scientific discussions with other authors. When finalizing the article and filling it with the author's conclusions, judgments and suggestions, it is recommended to compare them with what is described in the works of other scientists dealing with this problem. Conclusions, the interest of the readership. Taking into account all the above, this peer-reviewed material is not a scientific article and cannot be recommended for publication. Serious thorough revision is required, after which the issue of the possibility of publication may be considered and submitted for re-review. Research on this topic is of interest to the scientific community, but only on condition that they contain author's and reasonable proposals for solving existing problems (this is not in the reviewed material).
Second Peer Review
Peer reviewers' evaluations remain confidential and are not disclosed to the public. Only external reviews, authorized for publication by the article's author(s), are made public. Typically, these final reviews are conducted after the manuscript's revision. Adhering to our double-blind review policy, the reviewer's identity is kept confidential.
The list of publisher reviewers can be found here.
The subject of the research in the reviewed material is the issues of tax incentives for economic growth in the Russian Federation. The research methodology is based on the study of the literature on the research topic, the analysis of data on the rates of economic growth in different countries and the receipt of tax revenues to the budget system of the Russian Federation. The authors attribute the relevance of the work to the fact that, since 2000, special attention has been paid to ensuring economic growth in our country, and the excess of economic growth rates in Russia over the global average by 2030, while maintaining macroeconomic stability, is defined as one of the indicators for achieving the country's development goals. The scientific novelty of the reviewed study, according to the reviewer, consists in outlining the features of tax incentives for economic growth in Russia in connection with the new industrial revolution and digitalization of the economy and determining its promising directions, as well as the transition proposed by the authors from incentives through the mechanism of taxation of corporate profits to tax incentives that encourage investment and innovation through other, more reliable means mechanisms in the conditions of digitalization. The authors demonstrate the indicators of economic growth in modern Russia, note their instability, accompany the presentation of the material with a graphical representation of information on the dynamics of economic growth indicators in 2010-2021 in different countries, obtained on the basis of analysis of World Bank data; they rightly note that a series of exogenous shocks has determined new conditions for the development of Russia, which require and make possible the adoption of cardinal solutions in a wide variety of areas, including in the practice of tax incentives for economic growth. The article reflects the main provisions of the theory of economic growth, the views of foreign and domestic authors on the problem under study, as well as various tools to stimulate economic growth, such as depreciation policy, investment tax deduction for corporate income tax, investment tax credit and others. the problem of inefficiency of investment tax incentives currently in force in Russia. Noteworthy are the results of calculations of indicators of sensitivity and elasticity of tax revenues in 2022 in the Russian Federation, indicating that gradually tax revenues are becoming less sensitive to a decrease in GDP. Based on this, it is concluded that the tax incentives for economic growth embedded in the current mechanism of corporate income tax in times of crisis and recession are losing their importance for many taxpayers, since the tax itself is not paid or is paid in relatively small amounts due to a reduction in the tax base, which led the authors to the need making proposals formulated based on the results of the study. The bibliographic list includes 30 sources – publications of foreign and domestic scientists on the topic of the article, regulatory materials and Internet resources, to which there are address links in the text confirming the existence of an appeal to opponents. The following points should be noted as comments. Firstly, the text is not structured properly, it does not highlight such generally accepted sections in modern journal scientific publications as Introduction, Material and methods, Research results and their discussion. Secondly, it may not be immediately clear to the reader what values the left and right scales reflect in Figure 2 – it is desirable to reflect the total amount of tax revenues on the graph, then it will become clear what the right scale is for. The article corresponds to the direction of the journal "Taxes and Taxation", reflects the results of the research conducted by the authors, contains elements of scientific novelty and practical significance, may arouse interest among readers, and is recommended for publication after some revision.
|